Capital Pollution Solution?
By JEFF GOODELL
Published: July 30, 2006 New York Times Magazine
Richard Sandor, chairman and
C.E.O. of the Chicago Climate Exchange, seems to be fond of green. His business
card and company stationery are trimmed in green; he wears green neckties.
Justin
Steele for The New York Times
Sandor
says that the commodities market is just the place for an environmental
revolution.
When
he is photographed by the news media, thereÕs lots of green in the frame: green
file folders, green paper, anything. For Sandor, it may be a way of signaling
that the Chicago Climate Exchange — a commodities market for an unusual kind
of commodity, greenhouse gas allowances — is more than just another
business venture. It is, as he describes it, the engine of an environmental
revolution.
Justin
Steele for The New York Times
Making a market: BP, whose Whiting, Ind., refinery is
shown here, participated in the design of the Chicago Climate Exchange but
ultimately didn't sign on.
But of course,
green is also the color of money. And Sandor, who has been called Òthe father
of financial futuresÓ for his role in creating interest-rate futures in the
1970Õs and who made a fortune during the boom years of the 80Õs at Drexel
Burnham Lambert, the firm of the junk-bond king Michael Milken, is also
familiar with that particular shade. However high-minded in principle, the
Chicago Climate Exchange is also about making a buck off the planetÕs looming
climate catastrophe.
Not
that thereÕs anything wrong with that. In fact, the trading of greenhouse gas
allowances, also known as carbon trading, may be capitalismÕs best answer to
the problem of global warming. To avoid a dangerous degree of climate change,
many scientists say, greenhouse gas emissions worldwide will have to be cut by
50 to 70 percent over the next 50 years. The only hope of achieving that, short
of an unforeseen technological breakthrough or the passage of draconian
environmental laws, is to inspire radical change in the economic system. In a
carbon-trading scheme, you must pay to pollute: price tags are placed on
greenhouse gas emissions and then the market (not the government) essentially
figures out the cheapest, most efficient way to reduce them. ÒThe beauty of
carbon trading,Ó Dan Dudek, chief economist at Environmental Defense, a
nonprofit advocacy group, explained to me, Òis that it takes a primal human
impulse — greed — and redirects it toward saving the planet rather
than destroying it.Ó
Last
year, the European Union set up a carbon-trading scheme, the E.U. E.T.S.
(Emission Trading Scheme), which, despite some recent problems in its teething
stage, may reach $30 billion in market activity by the end of this year. Many
economists speculate that a global carbon market could become the largest
commodities market in the world. If the Chicago Climate Exchange were to become
a major trading venue, as Sandor says he hopes it will, the commissions alone
could be worth many millions.
For
the time being, SandorÕs operation is somewhat more modest. The exchange, also
known as CCX, opened for business in December 2003, after raising $25 million
in a public offering on the Alternative Investment Market, a part of the London
Stock Exchange. By May of this year, more than six million carbon allowances
had been traded on the exchange, and the price for the allowances was hovering
between $3 and $5 per metric ton of carbon dioxide. CCX now has more than 175
participants, including corporations like American Electric Power, Ford,
Motorola, DuPont and I.B.M., as well as the state of New Mexico and six
American cities, including Portland, Ore., and Oakland and Berkeley, Calif.
Sandor says that in 2004, the members of CCX reduced carbon emissions by 30
million metric tons, roughly equivalent to the yearly emissions of two big coal
plants. ÒCCX is growing,Ó the energy trading consultant Peter Fusaro told me
recently, Òbut compared with mature exchanges like the New York Mercantile
Exchange, the volumes are still minuscule.Ó
What
makes CCX exceptional, despite its small size, is that itÕs a private,
voluntary endeavor. In Europe, the E.U. E.T.S. is a multinational,
government-sanctioned project. The driving force behind the E.U. E.T.S. is a
carbon-trading scheme that is built into the Kyoto Protocol, the 1997
international agreement on climate change, which committed industrialized
nations to cutting greenhouse gas emissions by 5.2 percent from 1990 levels.
(KyotoÕs emissions oversight is not scheduled to kick in until 2008, but last
year the European Union set up the E.U. E.T.S. to help its members prepare for
that eventuality.) By contrast, in the United States, which has not ratified
Kyoto, there is no government-sanctioned carbon market.
Some
analysts, including Sandor, contend that itÕs just a matter of time before the
United States adopts some sort of national emissions-trading scheme. Pressure
is building on several fronts: environmentalists are demanding action on global
warming, investment banks covet the arbitrage opportunities that a carbon
market affords and international corporations seek long-term regulatory
certainty. ÒI think itÕs all but inevitable that a trading program will become
the tool of choice for managing emissions in the U.S.,Ó Christine Todd Whitman,
the former New Jersey governor and the administrator of the Environmental
Protection Agency early in the Bush administration, told me recently. ÒItÕs
just a question of when and how the program will be designed.Ó
Several
players are taking steps to design and implement trading schemes in the United
States. In effect, they are jockeying for what economists call Òfirst-mover
status,Ó hoping to create the prototype for what might become a future national
carbon market. A group of seven Eastern states have banded together to create a
regional greenhouse gas initiative, known as R.G.G.I., which is scheduled to
begin in 2009. In the West, a number of states, led by California, are
considering a similar initiative.
And
then thereÕs Sandor. No one has done more than he has to get a carbon market up
and running in the United States. The World Resources Institute, a private
environmental research group and an associate member of the exchange, has given
Sandor an endorsement. ÒThe Chicago Climate Exchange is an important experiment
in reducing greenhouse gas emissions,Ó the instituteÕs president, Jonathan
Lash, told me. Bill Richardson, the governor of New Mexico, whose state is a
participant in CCX, suggests that SandorÕs project is here to stay. ÒI think
the Chicago Climate Exchange is part of AmericaÕs future,Ó he said when I spoke
with him. ÒWe felt that the sooner we became a part of it, the better.Ó
But
some observers are more wary. Mark Trexler, an industry consultant who is an
advocate of emissions trading, told me that in SandorÕs rush to gain a foothold
in this growing market, he may be undermining the integrity and effectiveness
of the very system he presumes to advocate. It may be true that a market-based
system is an indispensable means for combating global warming, but does it
follow that an entrepreneur, no matter how well intentioned, can be trusted to
design that system for the public good? ÒMy fear is that if we arenÕt rigorous
enough in how we set up a trading system right now,Ó Trexler said, Òwe could
end up discrediting trading as a tool to deal with global warming. If weÕre not
careful, people could get the idea that itÕs all a fraud. And that would be a
disaster, both for us and for the planet.Ó
On
a recent morning, I visited Sandor in the CCX offices, which are housed in a
skyscraper designed by Philip Johnson on LaSalle Street in Chicago. Sandor, who
is 64, has a quick, practiced smile that suggests no lack of self-confidence.
He speaks plainly and seriously about the dangers of global warming, though at
times he can sound as if heÕs trying to sell you something — which, of
course, he is.
As
we talked in his office, I noticed a green silicone band on his right wrist. It
was similar to the yellow Live Strong wristband that Lance Armstrong
popularized to support his fight against cancer. It struck me as odd, since
Sandor didnÕt seem to be a wristband sort of guy. I asked him about it.
ÒItÕs
a CCX wristband,Ó he explained. ÒI never take it off. Want one?Ó
He
opened a drawer in his desk, took out a wristband in a plastic bag and handed
it to me. I opened it and read the slogan on the band: ÒCCX — To Save the
Planet.Ó
ÒThatÕs
a big job,Ó I said, poking fun at the immodesty of the slogan. ÒYouÕre serious
about this, arenÕt you?Ó
ÒVery
serious,Ó he said, stone-faced.
Sandor
began his career as an academic, teaching economics at the University of
California at Berkeley in the late 60Õs. Inspired in part by a credit crunch
that hit California in those years, he came up with the idea of interest-rate
futures, a financial instrument that would allow banks and investors to hedge
against future changes in interest rates. In 1972, he left academia and joined
the Chicago Board of Trade as an economist. In 1982, he followed the financial
boom to Wall Street, taking a job at Drexel, where he worked developing futures
markets in insurance and other fields. By 1990, however, Drexel was in
bankruptcy, and Sandor turned his attention elsewhere: to environmental
problems and how market mechanisms might be used to solve them.
SandorÕs
interest was sparked by the Environmental Protection AgencyÕs 1990 Acid Rain
Program, which sought to reduce sulfur dioxide emissions from coal-burning
power plants in the United States. The design of the program was ingenious but
simple. Instead of trying to regulate sulfur dioxide emissions the usual way,
by dictating a certain kind of emissions-control technology on each power
plant, the E.P.A. employed what is known as a cap-and-trade program. The agency
set an overall limit, or cap, on the amount of emissions permitted from all
power plants combined. Then it allotted a certain number of pollution
allowances to each emitter and let the operators of individual plants figure
out how they wanted to proceed. A company might install scrubbers or switch to
lower sulfur coal in order not to exceed its quota, but if the company
determined that polluting beyond its quota was necessary, it could buy
additional allowances from companies that had not used up their allotments.
Companies that reduced their emissions could bank their credits for later use
or sell them for a profit.
Fascinated,
Sandor joined the E.P.A.Õs Acid Rain Advisory Committee, which was charged with
helping to implement the new law. Among other things, Sandor persuaded the
E.P.A. to hold the annual auction for sulfur dioxide allowances on the exchange
run by his former employer, the Chicago Board of Trade. In the end, the
cap-and-trade program reduced pollutants more quickly, and far more cheaply,
than anyone anticipated and became the model for market-based environmental
success. Best of all, it helped transform the problem of reducing pollution
from a moral issue into a pragmatic one.
Not
long after the acid-rain program began, Sandor and other economists began
thinking about how to apply the same market-based strategies to an even bigger
problem, with an even bigger potential market: global warming. Whereas sulfur
dioxide is a pollutant emitted from a measurable number of specific
smokestacks, greenhouse gases, which are commonly measured in metric tons of
carbon dioxide equivalent, are emitted from millions of diverse sources,
including cars, jets, farm animal waste, factories and power plants. And unlike
sulfur dioxide, which is a regional pollutant, greenhouse gases are a global
problem: a metric ton of carbon dioxide emitted in Russia has the same impact
on the atmosphere as a metric ton emitted in Ohio.
Despite
these critical differences, in principle the same market-based approach could
be used. First, set the overall limit of greenhouse gases that countries are
collectively permitted to emit, then distribute (or auction off) allowances
among various pollution sources within each country and sit back and watch the
emitters trade those allowances as their needs and market strategies dictate.
There would even be room for speculators to join in the market: if you think
next summer is going to be a scorcher, you might buy up allowances on the
theory that in hot weather, coal plants often run at maximum capacity to meet
the power demand, dumping more carbon dioxide into the atmosphere and thus raising
the demand (and the price) for carbon allowances.
A
key innovation in the design of carbon markets was the idea of offsets. The
basic concept was that polluters could earn emissions credits not only by
cutting their own carbon emissions but also by assisting in efforts to reduce
emissions from other sources elsewhere in the world: for instance, by paying
farmers to reduce the emission of methane, a potent greenhouse gas, from animal
waste. Another example of an offset was the so-called natural carbon sink
— something like a forest, which absorbs carbon dioxide through
photosynthesis. If you increase the absorption of carbon dioxide with plants,
you create the same net effect on the atmosphere as cutting emissions from your
car — so why not allow polluters to earn credits for, say, investing in
reforestation?
The
use of offsets also added the possibility for greater profits and speculation
by carbon traders. For instance, if the price for carbon emissions credits is,
say, $15 a metric ton, a company that can buy or lease land in Brazil and plant
trees that will sequester carbon for the equivalent of $2 a metric ton stands
to make a tidy sum by selling the credits it can generate.
Policy
makers in the United States were excited by the idea of carbon trading, and
during the mid-1990Õs, American negotiators pushed hard to make sure the
framework for a carbon-trading scheme was included in the Kyoto Protocol.
Sandor, for his part, was eager to capitalize on a global carbon market and
began dreaming up the idea for an all-electronic exchange for carbon trading.
In 2000, with a $450,000 grant from the Joyce Foundation, a private
organization with a history of financing environmental initiatives, he enlisted
about 100 people — power-industry executives, environmentalists, lawyers
— to study the feasibility of establishing a voluntary market in advance
of what he assumed would eventually be a mandatory emissions-trading scheme in
the United States. In theory, his market would give companies practice
measuring and managing their greenhouse gas emissions, preparing them for life
in a carbon-constrained world. It would also put him in a position to be the
dominant trading platform when the American market opened in earnest.
SandorÕs
first challenge was to recruit companies to join the exchange, and his ace in
the hole was American Electric Power, or A.E.P. Sandor, it so happened, had
joined A.E.P.Õs board of directors at about the same time as the design process
for CCX was getting under way. Not surprisingly, in 2000, A.E.P. enlisted in
CCX and was joined by a number of other blue-chip corporations, including Ford
and I.B.M.
In
2001, the Bush administration threw CCX a curve when it declined to ratify
Kyoto. As a result, when CCX opened for business in 2003, it became virtually
the only carbon-trading game in town for the foreseeable future. As with the
trading scheme regulated by Kyoto, CCX brokers trades for credits of the six
main greenhouses gases; its transactions are audited by N.A.S.D., a respected
private securities industry regulator; and it has links to the E.U. E.T.S.,
where Sandor also runs an exchange. Unlike Kyoto, however, CCX has no teeth: it
is an entirely private effort. In the first full month of trading on CCX,
credits for about 82,000 metric tons of greenhouse gases swapped hands at a
price of about $1 per metric ton. ÒIt was a little like the Wright brothers at
Kitty Hawk,Ó Sandor told me. ÒNobody believed it would fly. But it did. Maybe
not elegantly at first, but it flew.Ó
Not
everyone was so upbeat about CCX. When the exchange first began recruiting
companies to join and soliciting environmental groups for endorsements, several
of those groups started to have reservations. The Natural Resources Defense
Council and Environmental Defense kept their distance. The Nature Conservancy
consulted on the rules for CCXÕs forestry offsets but did not join the
exchange. The concern, several members of these groups told me, was that the
initial design of CCX was too industry-friendly. Of its participating emitters,
CCX required emissions reductions of just 1 percent a year during the marketÕs
first phase, from 2003 to 2006. (This was far more modest than even the gentle
cuts mandated under Kyoto.) CCXÕs trading scheme threatened no explicit
penalties for companies that missed their targets; in fact, a provision was
included in the exchangeÕs rule book stating that emissions more than 4 percent
over a companyÕs baseline (today itÕs 7 percent) would not even be counted.
Finally, the rules that governed the use of offsets, critics said, were lax.
ÒClearly, the initial goal was to make it as painless as possible for companies
to sign up,Ó the industry consultant Mark Trexler told me. ÒIf youÕre designing
a voluntary system, itÕs hard to do it any other way.Ó
Despite
the claim that industry had a strong influence on the design of CCX, many of
the biggest emitters — including companies with solid environmental
credentials, like BP, the global oil and gas conglomerate, and Cinergy, the
Midwestern electric-power company — declined to sign on. There were a
variety of reasons given for this, but one of the most important issues very
likely concerned something called the emissions baseline. In any trading
scheme, picking a baseline — the point from which emissions increases and
reductions are measured — is controversial. In the Kyoto Protocol, for
instance, all reductions are measured against a baseline of emissions levels in
1990. For its baseline, CCX decided to use an average of emissions from 1998 to
2001. As it happened, one of the big nuclear plants of A.E.P. was mostly shut
down during those years, meaning that A.E.P. had to burn more coal to make up
for it, presumably inflating its carbon dioxide emissions. Thus, the choice of
an artificially high 1998-2001 baseline was a benefit to A.E.P. (on whose board
Sandor sits), since it could more easily remain below it.
Bruce
Braine, vice president for strategic policy analysis at A.E.P. and a CCX board
member, told me that Òthe question of establishing baselines is always
difficult. No matter how you choose to set them, someone complains that itÕs
unfair.Ó But as I was told by one former executive for CCX, who was granted
anonymity because the executive was not authorized to discuss CCXÕs internal
matters, Òother big emitters had no interest in joining a program that seemed
designed to help A.E.P. look like a good corporate citizen.Ó
In
the three years that CCX has been in operation, criticisms from
environmentalists have only grown. This is particularly the case with CCXÕs
standards for using agricultural offsets, in which carbon is sequestered in
farmland soils and then sold for emissions credits. Agricultural offsets are
notoriously difficult to measure and quantify, and a less-than-rigorous program
is essentially a way of introducing overvalued emissions allowances into the
trading system. Advocates of carbon trading like Environmental Defense have
worked hard to develop stringent protocols for soil sequestration, while
others, like David Doniger, the climate policy director at the Natural
Resources Defense Council, remain skeptical of the whole concept. ÒThe problem
with these kinds of offsets is that weÕve never found a way to separate the
wheat from the chaff,Ó Doniger told me. ÒThere is a constant tension between
quality control and high participation rate. And itÕs usually quality that goes
in the toilet.Ó
To
check this out for myself, on a rainy afternoon this spring I drove a few hours
southwest of Omaha to visit Steve Wiese, a 51-year-old farmer who earns extra
money by sequestering carbon on his 2,500-acre farm and selling the carbon
allowances on CCX. When I arrived, Wiese was going over some paperwork in his
barn. On his desk was a check for $2,008.94. ÒIt just came in the mail the
other day,Ó Wiese said, waving it happily.
Wiese,
like hundreds of other farmers who are getting paychecks from carbon emitters
by way of CCX, practices a form of cultivation known as no-till. Instead of
tearing up the fields each spring and releasing the carbon stored in the soil
(mostly in the form of decomposing plant matter and roots), no-till farmers
plant right over the previous yearÕs crop, leaving the soil undisturbed.
ÒHow
long have you been no-tilling?Ó I asked him.
ÒAbout
14 years,Ó he said, leaning back in his chair.
ÒHow
long have you been getting paid by CCX?Ó
ÒJust
signed up last year,Ó he said.
Here
was an instance of a major problem that critics of CCX have raised: Wiese is
getting paid for storing carbon in his soil, even though he has done nothing to
increase the amount of carbon that is being stored on his land — heÕs
just doing exactly what heÕs been doing for the last 14 years. A polluter like
A.E.P. or Ford can use a credit from WieseÕs farm to offset their greenhouse gas emissions,
but the fact is, in cases like these the payments from CCX are having no net
effect on the level of greenhouse gases in the atmosphere.
And
Wiese is hardly alone. Of the half-dozen farmers I spoke to in Nebraska and
Iowa, all had started no-tilling before they ever received a check from CCX.
When I asked Sandor about this, he argued that it doesnÕt matter if these
agricultural reductions are ÒrealÓ or not, because they make up only a small
fraction of CCXÕs overall reductions. ÒWhatÕs important,Ó he told me, Òis to
incentivize people who are doing the right thing. I think of these payments as
a kind of Ôtickler.Õ Ó To critics like Doniger, though, the problem is that
Sandor doesnÕt advertise these kinds of offsets as a ÒticklerÓ — he
advertises them as actual improvements in the atmosphere.
Environmentalists
have also raised questions about another aspect of CCX: how it calculates
emissions reductions. Sandor regularly notes that CCX members reduced carbon
emissions by 14 million metric tons in 2003 and 30 million metric tons in 2004.
(2005 numbers arenÕt available yet.) That is, of course, a good thing. But itÕs
not clear that CCX should get the credit.
Consider
the case of DuPont. Overall, DuPontÕs carbon dioxide emissions are down 72
percent since 1990 — an example, according to Edwin Mongan, the director
of energy and environment at DuPont, of Òwhat a company can do if it sets its
mind to it.Ó DuPont has beat its CCX baseline by more than 50 percent, cutting
emissions by 8 million metric tons more than required. ÒWeÕre supportive of CCX
because it has given us experience trying out selling, working in a carbon
market,Ó Mongan told me. But he also suggested that being a member of CCX has
not, in itself, led to reduced emissions. ÒI think CCX has been most valuable
to us in helping to certify and validate the emissions cuts that weÕve already
made,Ó he said.
The
fact that companies like DuPont are reducing their carbon emissions does not
mean that the emissions reductions trumpeted by CCX are necessarily unreal. But
it may mean that these reductions are mostly the result of good corporate
citizenship, not the power or efficiency of SandorÕs market.
Unfortunately,
sorting out the real from the unreal is not always easy with CCX projects. It
was precisely this difficulty that bothered David Littell, the commissioner of
MaineÕs Department of Environmental Protection, when he heard a pitch from CCX
in 2004. At the time, CCX had approached a number of states about joining the
exchange. Maine, which was among the first states to take progressive action on
global warming, was a coveted recruit for CCX. Littell told me that he and
other state administrators were Ògenerally supportiveÓ of CCXÕs goals but had
concerns that the exchange Òwas a system set up by private entities, with
private transactions, set up to ensure confidentiality.Ó Why was this a
problem? ÒIt creates an appearance that the emission reductions might not be
enforceable and verifiable,Ó Littell told me. Like several other Eastern states
that were courted, Maine didnÕt sign up.
Instead,
Littell is now concentrating on the creation of R.G.G.I., the regional
greenhouse gas initiative that also involves Connecticut, Delaware, New
Hampshire, New Jersey, New York and Vermont. Unlike with CCX, which was devised
essentially behind closed doors by a group of corporations, the creation of the
rules for R.G.G.I. has been open and transparent, with dozens of public
meetings and ample time for all stakeholders — environmentalists,
industrialists, politicians, citizens — to comment on the programÕs design.
As a result, the program is proceeding cautiously; for instance, instead of
allowing a wide variety of offsets, as CCX does, the R.G.G.I. program will
begin with a limited set of five categories of offsets (including collecting
methane from landfills) and does not include the controversial agricultural
offsets. ÒWe believe public confidence in the program is vital,Ó Franz Litz, of
the New York State Department of Environmental Conservation, told me.
If
CCX has such troubling flaws, why has it attracted so much support,
particularly in corporate America? One explanation, provided by Sandor and
others who endorse CCX, is that by joining CCX, companies get valuable
experience managing emissions in a functioning market. In addition, of course,
there is the public-relations benefit that goes along with being part of an
enterprise that is widely viewed as part of the solution, not part of the
problem.
But
whatÕs going on here may be more complicated than that, and it has to do with
that other shade of green. The logic goes like this: in a few years, if a
mandatory carbon-trading system is finally established in the United States,
one of the most contentious issues in the design of that system will be how
companies that have already made reductions in their emissions will be credited
for those reductions — if indeed they are credited at all. In other
words, should a company like DuPont or I.B.M., both good corporate citizens
that have already made sizable cuts in emissions, be required to reduce
greenhouse gas emissions just as much as a competitor who has done nothing? If
they do get credit for those early reductions, how might that credit be
measured? For DuPont and I.B.M., hundreds of millions of dollars could be at
stake in how this question is resolved.
With
CCX, Sandor has effectively played this uncertainty to his advantage. The
bigger CCX gets, the more cities and states it can get to join, the more likely
it will be that carbon credits on the exchange will be viewed as the de facto
standard by politicians and others responsible for designing a national system
— and the more likely it will be that credits on the exchange, which at
the moment are only informally recognized among CCX participants, will be
grandfathered into a national system and granted full legal status as property
rights. ÒThis is all about business,Ó one carbon-market veteran told me. ÒIt
has nothing to do with the environment.Ó
To
Sandor, these criticisms of CCX are, if not trivial, then at least beside the
point. ÒAt a certain level, all this becomes a debate about how many angels can
dance on the head of a pin,Ó he told me. ÒIn the larger scheme of things, they
are meaningless. Global warming is an extremely urgent problem. Is CCX perfect?
Of course not. Neither was the U.S. Constitution — they forgot the 10
amendments, including freedom of the press and freedom of speech. The important
point here is that markets work to solve problems. The sooner we admit that,
and the sooner we get around to building those markets, the better.Ó
Not
long ago, at the University of Minnesota campus in Minneapolis, I was part of a
standing-room-only crowd gathered in an auditorium to hear Sandor speak. He
took the podium and charmed the audience with a mix of business savvy and
social conscience. His message was one of hope and confidence and creativity, a
response to the people he calls the Darth Vaders of the world — all those
environmentalists, politicians and businessmen who think that global warming is
too difficult an issue to tackle, who believe we have to wait longer and study
it more before we do anything and, most of all, who are determined to make the
perfect the enemy of the good.
If
CCX were simply a giant eBay, there would be nothing to do but celebrate
SandorÕs gumption and step back and see if his vision had wings. But creating a
market for public goods is different from creating a market for Elvis
memorabilia. Sandor is in the business of commodifying the air we breathe, and
in that regard he is indeed a revolutionary, pushing the boundary between
public and private and, in the process, raising new questions about what
capitalism can and cannot do. ItÕs easy to see how a carbon market might be
designed to enrich traders and investment banks; what is still far from clear
is whether one can be designed that will significantly reduce greenhouse gas
emissions. It may seem paradoxical, but the real lesson of CCX could turn out
to be that markets may be wonderfully efficient systems, but they are no
substitute for strong government action — both in setting the broad social
goals of how to deal with global warming and, in the case of carbon markets,
ensuring that the rules are not inclined in favor of private interests.
ÒIntegrity
is the linchpin to both public and investor confidence,Ó the emissions-trading
pioneer Dan Dudek told me. ÒWithout integrity, investors wonÕt commit serious
capital either to generate the supply of reductions necessary for trading or to
buy the reductions in the first place.Ó
Sandor
doesnÕt disagree. ÒThis is just the beginning of a long journey,Ó he told me as
we walked down the Minnesota campus steps after the speech. He was, as usual,
in a hurry, his BlackBerry in hand, heading to California and Asia in the
coming days. A black sedan waited at the curb. ÒI donÕt pretend to have all the
answers,Ó he said, reaching for the door. ÒIÕm just a humble economist. All I
want to do is solve the problem of global warming.Ó
Jeff Goodell, a frequent contributor to the
magazine, is the author of ÒBig Coal: The Dirty Secret Behind AmericaÕs Energy
Future.Ó
externality | external side-effects | examples